Research
CBDC and the international position of the euro
The international position of the euro is under pressure. The introduction of a digital euro, especially when this can be used for international transactions, will strengthen the position of the euro.

Introduction
Worldwide, central banks are preparing to introduce digital central bank money (Central Bank Digital Currency or CBDC). This concerns a new digital variant as a supplement to the existing money. The European Central Bank (ECB) is now also working on a digital euro. It differs from the current book money (checking deposits, bank accounts) in that the digital euro is an obligation of the central bank, just like the banknotes it issues. Book money, the money held in a bank account, is the liability of a retail bank and therefore appears on the balance sheet of the banking system. CBDC is sometimes described as a digital version of a banknote, but that representation is too simple. CBDC is more complex and it will not have the characteristics of a banknote in all respects. However, in due course the digital euro will have a value of one euro, just like the cash and book money variety.
CBDC also has a geopolitical dimension
So far, CBDC is mainly discussed in the context of the existing financial system and the impact it may have on payments and the position of banks and central banks. In contrast, the potential geopolitical impact of a digital euro has received significantly less attention so far. This mainly concerns the consequences that the presence or absence of a digital euro could have on the international position of the euro in the long term.
The European Union (EU) has indicated that it aims to achieve what is known as strategic autonomy. This broad term suggests that it is primarily about a high degree of economic, political and military independence. But a well-developed, globally used currency can also contribute to the political independence of the EU. However, this requires that this currency also has its own independent international payment infrastructure. Otherwise the political influence of a country is strongly undermined, as I will explain further on. The euro does not yet have that position. A well-developed digital euro is not only necessary to strengthen the international position of the euro, but can also ensure that this position is not eroded by the rise of the Chinese renminbi.
In this special, I will first briefly discuss the international position of the euro. Next, the international, financial infrastructure is discussed, with special attention to the dollar's position in it and China's efforts to strengthen the international role of the renminbi. This is followed by a discussion of the international dimension of CDBC and in particular its wholesale variant. I end with a conclusion.
The international position of the euro is stagnating
The euro has been a major currency from the first day of its existence. It is true that the US dollar is still by far the most important currency in the world, but the euro is a close second (Table 1). However, unlike the euro, the dollar is a truly global currency. This is reflected, for example, in the fact that many countries worldwide manage their exchange rates against the dollar. Also, many international transactions, such as those in commodities, are settled overwhelmingly in US dollars. In contrast, the international use of the euro is mainly limited to countries in the immediate European area and in Africa, where the CFA franc is tightly pegged to the euro.
Table 1: The international position of the euro in perspective (%)

However, a closer look reveals that the international position of the euro is stagnating. This can be gauged, for example, from the share of the euro as a reserve currency. This is not substantially larger in 2021 than the combined share of its constituent currencies in 1999 (such as the German mark, the Dutch guilder, the French franc and the Italian lira), when the euro was introduced. This is despite the fact that the euro area has since grown from 11 to 19 countries. One reason for the stagnation of the euro's development is the unfinished nature of the eurozone. The Banking Union is still incomplete, as is the Capital Market Union, which suffers from the absence of a well-developed market for EMU-wide common safe assets (securities issued by the EU with a guarantee from all member states). The first serious steps in this area were only taken in 2020 with the issuance of so-called ‘corona bonds’ by the European Commission. In times of turmoil, many investors still take into account the so-called ‘redenomination risk’, i.e. the risk that the eurozone will break up and the euro will cease to exist.
Unique position of dollar contributes to US power
The dominance of the US dollar gives the United States (US) considerable political power. This became apparent, for example, in 2018, when the US government imposed sanctions against Iran because of its nuclear program. The EU did not agree, but could only watch as European business nevertheless conformed to US policy. It did this to avoid being hit by sanctions itself. This example illustrates that, when all is said and done, the strategic autonomy of the EMU is still a long way off. The US recently threatened, in response to the Ukraine crisis, to have Russia excluded from participation in the international payment system SWIFT[1] The US has good visibility into the behavior of foreign companies because virtually all international payments are processed through SWIFT. Now the EU and the US agree in many respects in international politics. But that is not necessarily always the case. Furthermore, it would be extremely unfavorable for the EU if the Chinese renminbi took over the international role from the dollar.
[1] Note that SWIFT is a Belgium-based cooperative of several hundred international banks. The US has a lot of influence there, partly because in almost all cases either the dollar is used, a US bank is involved as a correspondent bank, or US software is used somewhere along the chain
International position of dollar crumbles, renminbi rises
For the time being, however, the international position of the dollar is still unassailable. It is now slowly but surely eroding, partly because the US can now call itself the world's largest debtor in absolute terms. Also as a percentage of GDP, the US international asset position has now sharply deteriorated (see Figure 2).
Figure 1: Share of euro, US dollar and renminbi in international reserves (%)

The fact that the dollar is nevertheless still the leading currency by a distance is mainly because no full-fledged alternative has emerged so far. However, China is working hard to develop the renminbi into a good alternative to the dollar. At present, the Chinese currency is still a relative dwarf currency, even relative to the euro (see Figure 1). However, China is systematically working to strengthen its currency. In less than 40 years, the country has managed to move up from one lagging in almost every aspect, with huge poverty, to one of the largest and most financially powerful economies in the world. It is also a wealthy country, with substantial foreign claims. Militarily, it can now increasingly compete with the traditional superpowers, and this trend is accelerating. In short, there is every reason to also take the rise of the Chinese renminbi seriously. After all, in a number of ways China currently resembles the US of 75 years ago more than the US itself. Things can move fast, and the first steps on the renminbi's long march have been taken.
Figure 2: The international asset position of the US (1976 - 2020)

China also steps up pressure on the euro
Compared to traditional industrialized countries, China is far ahead in the adoption of digital central bank money. This too should be seen in geopolitical perspective, although it may not be apparent at first glance. After all, the stagnant development of the euro as an international currency, as outlined above, was not primarily caused by the absence of a digital euro, nor will its arrival simply fix it. But the international position of the euro does risk being put under pressure by the arrival of the DCEP, a digital version of the renminbi, because China has been using it as a geopolitical tool from the outset. The DCEP, which has been in the testing phase for quite some time, will not only be used in China itself, but it seems that it could soon be used to settle international transactions. This allows African exporters to get their goods exported to China paid for directly in DCEP. This in turn allows them to purchase products and services in China. It seems that such transactions can soon be carried out through the DCEP without the intervention of SWIFT or even their own central bank. In doing so, they will evade observation by the Americans. For countries that want to avoid sanctions, or otherwise believe that the US does not need to be able to observe everything, the DCEP can offer a very welcome alternative. Think of major commodity exporters like Iran and Russia, or some African countries. Arms transactions will also soon be able to be financially handled through this circuit, out of the sight of the US. It will stimulate the international use of the (digital) renminbi. In particular, the way in which China, from the outset, wants to promote the use of the DCEP in Africa, can be seen as a targeted action to undermine the position of the euro. Indeed, it must be remembered that the CFA franc, which is an important aspect of the European orientation of much of Africa, is not popular in many countries in the CFA zone. This is because, in large parts of Africa, the CFA zone is mostly seen as a relic of colonial times.
What determines the international position of a currency?
History shows that the international use of a currency is partly based on three pillars, namely the strength of the economy, political influence, based on military power, and financial development.[2]
With this come two important observations. One is that markets are fairly inert. That is, market participants stick to existing practices for a long time. Once a currency is accepted as the dominant anchor currency, markets continue to treat it as such, even as the original foundations beneath it slowly erode. For example, England's dominance under the gold standard had steadily eroded over time, but the pound officially retained its status as the leading currency until 1931 when the United Kingdom left the gold standard. By then the country had been overtaken economically, and even surpassed by some other countries (such as the United States and initially Germany), had emerged impoverished from World War I, and was no longer militarily dominant. After World War II, it was abundantly clear that the United States was the absolute economic and military superpower, and the dollar took over the role of the British pound. Since then, however, American dominance in these areas has steadily declined. Today, the importance of the dollar in the global financial system is significantly greater than can be based on its weight in the world economy. China is ‘the new kid in town’. The second observation is, that the transition from one anchor currency to another is not necessarily smooth. This applies not only to the transition from pound to dollar, but also to earlier periods when major currencies, such as the Dutch guilder in a more distant past, fell from their pedestals.
[2] The currencies that could develop into truly global money – notably the British pound during the gold standard and the US dollar since 1945, both of which were the currencies of the most politically influential country at the time – were carried by the largest and best-developed economy with the most advanced financial system (well-developed markets, strong, internationally-operating financial institutions, net claims on foreign countries) and were backed by a powerful military apparatus that could project power globally, for example through control of international sea and trade routes.
The international dimension of CBDC
As explained earlier, in a well-developed financial system, such as the Dutch one, CBDC has little added value for domestic payments. This may change if the use of cash were to decline further and, in extremis, disappear. In countries with low financial inclusion, which means that many people have no access to banking services such as a payment, credit or savings facility, the situation is already substantially different. These are mostly emerging markets. But for all countries, CBDC can help to better facilitate cross-border payments. A well-designed CBDC can also help to protect a country's monetary autonomy by preventing private ‘stable coins’ from growing so large that the central bank loses control over the money supply and financial stability.[3] This plays into both retail and wholesale CBDC.
The international dimension of retail CBDC
By retail CBDC we mean a digital currency issued by the central bank and developed for domestic payments. It is in a one-to-one relationship with the existing cash and book money. Residents, mainly private individuals and small businesses, can hold a balance at the central bank. Central banks see CBDC as a complement to existing cash and non-cash money. It is currently not yet clear what the European CBDC, the digital euro, will look like exactly, and how large the CBDC circuit will be compared to existing money.
Thus, although retail CBDC is predominantly aimed at domestic residents, it will also have an international dimension. From the outset, non-residents will also want to use it. Think for example of tourists, who when visiting our country can now also pay with cash euros. Furthermore, there are temporary residents or non-residents with family in our country who would like to hold an account in digital euros. More importantly, central banks also seem to be working on linking national CBDC networks together. Then, for example, someone could quickly and cheaply transfer money from his euro-denominated CBDC account at the ECB to a CBDC account of a relation at a foreign bank and denominated, for example, in US dollars, Swedish crowns or British pounds. Such payments now go through the correspondent banking circuit of the banks or through specialized payment companies. Today, these transactions are relatively slow and expensive.[4][5]
If central banks can market a reliable, fast and cheap alternative to this, it is good news for citizens. CBDC may therefore be an opportunity to shorten the chain of correspondent banks, simplify mutual clearing and bring regulations more in line with each other. For the banks and other financial parties operating here, of course, this means that a source of revenue dries up. The amounts can be substantial. When El Salvador decided in June 2021 to introduce Bitcoin as legal tender, alongside the dollar, the main reason was that it could save substantially on remittances from abroad. Salvadorans living in the US transfer large sums of money to their families every year using the process described above. By converting the money into Bitcoin, sending it via the blockchain to their families, who then convert it back into dollars, they expect to save about USD 200 million in costs annually. At least that is the expectation. Incidentally, via a CBDC-based circuit, in this case a digital dollar to be issued by the Salvadoran central bank, between central banks this could be done just as well and quickly, but without the price risk between Bitcoin and dollar.
The international dimension of wholesale CBDC
Wholesale CBDC is less tightly defined than retail CBDC. It is similar to the liquidity reserves that banks currently hold with the central bank. These reserves are used for the interbank settlement of payment transactions. These reserves will therefore certainly be part of wholesale CBDC in the future, as will the balances held at the central bank by, for example, securities settlement firms. But wholesale CBDC is likely to include more than just liquidity reserves as we already know them today. It may also include, for example, CBDC balances held at the central bank by certain financial institutions, such as mutual funds, pension funds and insurers, and large industrial companies. In addition, wholesale CBDC is characterized by relatively high amounts and low transaction numbers, while retail CBDC will mainly involve a lot of transactions with relatively low amounts.
[3] A stablecoin is a covered crypto currency, meaning that (in theory) its value is determined by high-quality financial assets, purchased with the traditional money deposited.
[4] This inertia arises because several links (parties) are involved in the chain. The parties involved also make a profit when exchanging one currency for another. Furthermore, there are (large) differences in laws and regulations in different countries. For example, there are differences in the implementation of Anti-Money Laundering (AML) and Know Your Customer (KYC) regulations. Furthermore, the settlement of interbank transactions does not take place in the same way everywhere. Moreover, the opening hours of the various currencies are different and the message standards may also differ.
[5] Incidentally, many companies are already less dependent on the relatively poorly developed correspondent banking systems because they already maintain checking accounts with foreign banks.
The role of SWIFT and the alternatives of Russia and China
Most international payments between professional parties are settled through the so-called SWIFT system. The market position of SWIFT is strong, the company seems to have a de facto global monopoly in this area. Yet there are plenty of parties who would like to make their international payments outside of SWIFT. Founded in 1973, SWIFT is an international cooperative under Belgian law. It settles transactions quickly and reliably and their systems are almost always available. In practice, however, as explained above, the US has a great deal of influence over it. They can monitor transactions in SWIFT and also have the power to exclude countries from SWIFT, something they recently threatened Russia with as a sanction in case the Ukraine crisis gets out of hand. Earlier, I mentioned the example that when the US imposed sanctions on Iran, many European companies felt compelled to comply, even though the EU did not join the US sanctions politically. If central banks manage to link their national CBDC systems, a scenario is conceivable where international payments can also be settled relatively easily outside SWIFT.
If Eurozone countries had a good alternative to SWIFT using CBDC, it would significantly increase the EU's autonomy from the US. It would give European companies the opportunity to evade US sanctions and conform to the European political position if they wish. A downside is, of course, that countries with 'bad' regimes are now also developing alternatives to SWIFT. This would also give them the opportunity to evade sanctions, in whole or in part. With the digital renminbi, the DCEP, China seems to be opening up the possibility for foreign parties to pay directly in DCEP. Currently, Russia has already developed an alternative to SWIFT, SPFS. Although this is still at a relatively primitive stage, several countries have now been approached to join this network, including Belarus, Kazakhstan, Turkey and Iran. Talks are also underway with China to integrate SPFS with the Chinese alternative to SWIFT, CBIBPS. It would allow these countries, should they be affected by international sanctions, to still trade between themselves each other, out of sight of the US. This possibility could, for example, considerably undermine the imposition of sanctions against Russia, a major oil-exporting country. Furthermore, sources report that some banks in Germany and Switzerland are already connected to SPFS.[6]
These developments also help explain why the DCEP is enjoying a favorable reception in Africa. Several countries affected by US sanctions are in Africa. A high degree of acceptance of the DCEP in Africa will certainly strengthen the international position of the renminbi, which may be at the direct expense of the euro.
[6] Western governments could, of course, try to prohibit Western banks from participating in SPFS and CBIBPS, although it is an open question whether this could be done watertight. This might complicate the development of these alternatives to SWIFT, but in all likelihood would not stop it.
Conclusion
The biggest and most tangible effects of the advent of a digital euro will be visible in the domestic payments market and the banks' position in it. Yet, in various ways, the digital euro also affects the international position of the European single currency. First, it consolidates the central bank's position by preventing private stablecoins from undermining the central bank's monetary autonomy. Incidentally, this danger is especially prevalent in less-developed and financially less stable countries. In well-developed markets with a strong economy, a high degree of financial stability and an effective supervisory structure, such as the EMU, US and other industrialized countries, this is less of an issue. Second, a well-designed digital euro is an important precondition for the fulfilment of the strategic autonomy that the EU claims to aspire to. Noting again that strategic autonomy is a much broader concept. It requires not only the formulation of a strategic policy agenda, but also defines the preconditions within which the EU can determine and effectuate its position independently in all respects. This also requires, for example, substantial investments in defence and related industries, among others. But if it is possible, via a network of central banks (by connecting national CBDC systems) parallel to SWIFT, to facilitate international payments quickly and cheaply, this also increases the political independence of the EU. The downside of this is that it also makes it easier for countries against which sanctions have been imposed to circumvent them. Thirdly, there is a more defensive consideration. Now that an economic and geopolitical superpower like China is introducing a digital version of its currency and directly allowing foreign trading partners to make payments directly to their Chinese partners, other major countries cannot be left behind. If, in due course, the digital euro is not at least as user-friendly as the DCEP, it will undoubtedly damage the international position of the euro, and thus the autonomy of the EU.